Why Armen Alchian is the GOAT đ
Micro, Macro, Theory, Empirics, Researcher, Teacher. Alchian did it all.
You are reading Economic Forces, a free weekly newsletter on economics, especially price theory, without the politics. Economic Forces arrives weekly in the inboxes of over 11,000 subscribers. You can support our newsletter by sharing this free post or becoming a paid subscriber:
Tyler Cowen has a new online book out titled âGOAT: Who is the Greatest Economist of all Time, and Why Does it Matter?â While there are potential problems in treating ideas like basketball, the project is a fun, fast read overall. As the author of a newsletter with frequent gifs, Iâm all for encouraging light-hearted discussions of economics and economists (in addition to the super serious work that needs to be done).
What does it mean to be the GOAT, according to Tyler?
To qualify as âGOAT the greatest economist of all time,â I expect the following from a candidate. The economist must be original, of great historical import, serve as a creator and carrier of important ideas, have a hand in both theory and empirics, have a hand in both macro and micro, and be ânot too wrongâ on the substance of issues. Furthermore, the person also must be a pretty good economist! That is, if you sat down with the person and discussed economic issues, you would be in some way impressed.
I wonât spoil Tylerâs answer, but we see from the table of contents that main contenders are Milton Friedman, F.A. Hayek, J.M. Keynes, John Stuart Mill, Thomas Malthus, and Adam Smith.
Readers of Economic Forces (heck, readers of the title of this post) will notice that Armen Alchian, our newsletterâs avatar, is not on the list. Alchian isnât even on Tylerâs list of ânames who deserve greater consideration,â a list that includes Homer. Yes, the poet. I know Homer reads The Economist, but câmon! No mention of Alchian is a travesty! (It wouldnât be a GOAT discussion without some hyperbole.)
So here is my case for why Armen Alchian is the GOAT.
Original and Important Ideas
Alchian brought original thinking to the disciplines he touched from the very beginning of his career. In 1950, Alchian published "Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory." This paper developed evolutionary arguments long before other economists embraced biology. Alchianâs contribution should have helped us avoid many worthless debates around behavioral economics and rationality, but, alas. As Alchian points out, the important part is not that any person is super-rational and calculates optimal business decisions but that the profit and loss system weeds out those who choose decisions that lose money.
And thatâs not even what Alchian is known for. Alchian carved new ground by focusing economics on property rights, incentives, and information. He is most known for his papers from the 1960s and 1970s on property rights and transaction costs. Besides Coase, Alchian is the figure at the lead of these important schools of thought.
UCLA economics is a thing because of Alchian. The school stood as aâcarrier of important ideasâ (one attribute of the GOAT) against the paradigm of Samuelson and Keynes of the time. Transaction cost economics was a serious return to good economics (a point I will say more about later) that existed in earlier times.
Why do firms exist? That is a question of first-order importance for many fields of microeconomics. Alchian has two papers worth mentioning explicitly.
First, Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization with Harold Demsetz. This was chosen as one of AER's Top 20 articles in its first 100 years. The fundamental problem that Alchian and Demsetz point to is Hayekian. Alchian, once again, carrying important ideas. Information isn't free! With team production, paying each worker their marginal product isn't straightforward. People will specialize in monitoring and metering workers.
In another paper, with Benjamin Klein and Robert Crawford, Alchian points out that once workers and firms have invested in each other, there are rents to haggle over. Haggling is destructive. So workers and firms have the incentive to find contractual workarounds. The more investments are specific to a particular trading partner, the more likely we will see contracts tying the two sides more tightly together. One such contract? An integrated firm.
If we do not speak of a large school of property rights economics today, it is not because the school was proven wrong. Instead, in the areas closest to Alchianâs workâespecially the theory of the firmâtransaction costs are just part of the standard discussion.
Alchianâs focus on property rights and contracting is why he was also foundational for the development of law and economics as a field. So much so that the International Center for Law & Economics, where I work, is dedicated to the legacy of Armen Alchian.
Theory and Empirics
While best known as an economic theorist, Alchian also excelled at empirical work. Even his work on inflation was theoretical and empirical.
Alchian, like Friedman, was a statistician by training. In addition to his academic research, he worked as a consultant for the RAND Corporation. It was here that Armen Alchian famously did the first event study in economics, drawing on economic theory. He used public stock price data to learn top-secret information. He describes the episode as follows:
The year before the H-bomb was successfully created, we in the economics division at RAND were curious as to what the essential metal was â lithium, beryllium, thorium, or some other⌠For the last six months of the year prior to the successful test of the bomb, I traced the stock prices of those firms. I used no inside information. Lo and behold! One firmâs stock price rose, as best I can recall, from about $2 or $3 per share in August to about $13 per share in December. It was the Lithium Corp of America. In January I wrote and circulated [a memo]. Two days later I was told to withdraw it.
While he did not get credit for this empirical work until much later, the episode shows Alchianâs focus on looking at data to answer questions. Armen Alchian's 1963 Econometrica paper on progress curves showcases his exceptional skills as an empirical economist. He rigorously analyzes wartime airframe data using advanced (for the time) statistical tests, evaluates predictive accuracy, explores alternatives, and carefully examines practical implications and limitations. The paper exemplifies Alchian's talents in bridging theory and measurement to advance applied knowledge. While it is not the most cited empirical work today, it is often cited in the learning-by-doing literature, including Nobel Prize winner Ken Arrowâs work on in the area. When studying the history of learning by doing, Matthieu Ballandonne compared âthe different strategies for modeling learning developed in the 1950s and 1960s, showing the influence of RAND's and Armen Alchian's contributions on Arrow's use of a log-linear equation of learning and its introduction into an economic growth model.â
More than doing deep historical work that people still read today (like Friedman and Schwartzâs A Monetary History) or developing statistical tools that continue to be used, we can see Alchianâs âhand in empiricsâ through his expertise in what was jokingly called UCLA econometrics. What is UCLA econometrics? According to Nobel Prize winner Merton Miller, âYou go to Armen Alchian, and you ask, âArmen, is this number about right?â And Armen says, âYeah, that sounds right.â So you use that number.â Iâd trust Alchianâs sense of empirical work, which is far ahead of someone like Samuelson, Keynes, or Smith. And certainly, it has been more influential and important than Homerâs econometrics.
Macro and Micro
While most known for his work on the theory of the firm and transaction costs (which is heavily micro), Alchian also made important contributions to macroeconomics. Even his transaction costs work is important for macroeconomic theory. His paper on Information Costs, Pricing, and Resource Unemployment made several important contributions to macroeconomic thinking. The paper provided microfoundations for macro unemployment based on costly information and rational behavior by individuals. He models how costly information acquisition affects pricing decisions and unemployment equilibriums and why unanticipated inflation redistributes wealth and disrupts relative prices and employment. This insight anticipated many later macro models.
Two other macro papers are worth mentioning. His paper âWhy Money?â anticipated many ideas in modern search models of money. Again, we have a micro explanation of macro phenomena before the microfoundations revolution. Alchian and Ben Klein have a paper, âOn the Correct Measure of Inflation,â providing a theoretical foundation for a utility-constant intertemporal price index. They argue that, consistent with intertemporal economic theory, the index should include asset prices, not just current consumption goods. This would make measures of inflation more in line with modern economic models. Again, Alchian integrates micro and macro theory with empirical work.
Historical Impact
The one area where Alchian does not match some of the others discussed by Cowenâespecially Friedman and Keynesâis in terms of historical impact.
But even here, it is not as if Alchian had no impact, especially within economics as a field. Alchian's body of work laid the foundations for entire subfields, as we already mentioned. The UCLA tradition he started trained generations of economists who propagated Alchian's ideas. His fingerprints can be seen across fields like contract theory, law and economics, public choice, and industrial organization. He influenced economic education through his textbooks with Bill Allen. While the quantity of students influenced is not on par with Paul Samuelson, the textbook earned Alchian and Allen a strong fanbase among passionate economic educators, myself included. Few economists can claim such a broad historical impact on economics as a field.
Good Economist
The real reason Alchian deserves the award is that he was simply a good economist. Everyone who knew him says so.
Tyler knocks Smith down a little by asking
Is there any economics class where you can imagine wanting Smith as your tutor?Is there any economics class where you can imagine wanting Smith as your tutor? He might give fascinating feedback and drum up some generative insights, but is there any economic issue he can, in the counterfactual sense, analyze with much accuracy?
Alchian, by contrast, would be a great tutor for any class through his theoretical knowledge and empirical good sense.
Those who learned from Alchian rave about his economic reasoning skills. His Socratic teaching style forced students to think rigorously about their assumptions and logical chains. Alchian's classroom was an economics bootcamp, training students' sharp economic thinking. His critical eye and creativity made him a magnificent economist in his own right. He had so internalized economic reasoning that he could lead classes on the fly in a way few professors today would even dare.
His students, the ones that survived, constantly speak his praise. Nobel Prize winner William Sharpe, who took a graduate course taught by Alchian in 1956 called him a âbrilliant mind grappling (usually very successfully) with the most difficult concepts in economics in thoroughly creative and innovative ways.â
Very few, if any, economists can match Alchian's combination of originality, impact, ideas, contributions, and raw talent. His legacy continues through those he taught and concepts he pioneered. For trailblazing evolutionary thinking, instigating the property rights revolution, developing seminal ideas, impressive empirical work, commanding macro and micro, and teaching economics like no other, Armen Alchian has a rock-solid case as the Greatest Of All Time economist.
It is easy to find high praise for Alchian as an economic thinker, including from people Cowen considers in the GOAT conversation. According to Wikipedia, Anthony J. Culyer quoted Kenneth Arrow as saying Alchian was the âbrightest economics student Stanford ever had.â Not bad from Ken Arrow, who I hear was rather smart. Speaking of Nobel Laureates, in 1984, when F.A. Hayek was asked who his favorite economist was, he named two: George Stigler and Armen Alchian. Coase in the introduction to the first collection of his writings, Economic Forces at Work (great title, btw), wrote (HT Geoff Manne):
Alfred Marshall considered that it was an essential task of an economist to demonstrate 'the Many in the One, the One in the Many.' No modern economist has been more successful in accomplishing this than Armen Alchian.
This constant connection of many in the one and one in the many is what we try to follow here at Economic Forces with our approach to blending micro and macro. That comes directly from Alchian and what makes him the đ.
Who would you say is the GOAT? Comment below to let me know.
Armen is certainly the best economist I have known. Let me tell you a story. It was 1979, and I was in a cab in Washington DC with Mike Jensen and Fischer Black. (I was a lawyer at the time, and Mike and Fischer had been hired as consultants by a client.) We were stuck in traffic, so I had plenty of time to ask questions. I asked them two questions: Who is the most underrated economist in the world? Who is the most overrated economist in the world? Each thought for a while, and to my surprise they both had the same person for each category. I wonât comment on their most overrated economist (an incredibly well known economist), but both agreed the Armen was the most underrated economist in the world. They then started talking about all of Armenâs seminal contributions, many of which Brian mentions in his post. After some time, Fischer, a man of few words but deep thoughts, said âArmen Alchian is the foremost living micro-economist in the world today.â Mike then said, âI agree with you Fischer.â
At that time, I only knew of Armen in passing. Over the next several years, however, I got to know Armen well, first at conferences and then when he would visit his best friend, Bill Meckling, who was my dean. For some reason, Armen took me under his wing and would send me comments on my working papers. They were amazing comments--the best I ever received in my career.
I could spend hours talking about Armenâs strengths as an economist. Again, Brian has done a nice job in this dimension so I wonât repeat what he has written. Let me add what I see as one of Armenâs greatest strengths: his simplicity. He would always break a problem down to its most basic components: an individual making a choice in a world of scarcity. There is a total absence of jargon in all of Armenâs papers. He was trying to better understand the world. And at that task, I know of no one who was better.
Agree that Alchian belongs in this conversation. But it's very strange to me that there is no mention of Marx. On empirics, his hundred page chapter on the working day is masterful, with very creative use of data on height requirements in the British military to show health effects of the factory system on the working class. On theory, the model of expanded reproduction was a clear precursor to von Neumann's multisector growth model, and later work by Uzawa and others. His theory of endogenous technological change (labor saving as wages rise which expands the reserve army and lowers wages) has been influential in some of the business cycle literature, especially on long waves. Originality and influence are not in doubt, nor is macro and micro. Maybe Tyler thinks he was wrong on substance (based on predictions of a falling rate of profit, or immizerization and revolution) but even Schumpeter saw him as among the most significant of those who preceded him. Just my two cents.