You'll have to pry supply and demand from my cold, dead hands
Good old supply and demand still has a lot to teach us, even about labor markets š±
Thanks for subscribing to Economic Forces! I hope you enjoy our humble newsletter and we learn some economics together along the way.
My name is Brian Albrecht š and Iām an Assistant Professor of Economics at Kennesaw State University. Go Owls!
Next week, you will hear from my lovely and talented co-host, Josh Hendrickson. The plan is for us to alternate each Thursday (unless some idiotic economic commentary drives us to push the send button more often).
We are trying to keep this lighthearted and fun while still discussing important economic ideas. We hope you do too.
Iām kicking this shindig off with a simple defense of (the increasingly scoffed at by the loudest voices online) supply and demand. It seems silly to need to defend supply and demand within economics circles. But it is 2020ā¦
tl;dr We canāt forget how much supply and demand explains about labor markets, especially when teaching students in their first economics course.
I teach my intro economics students supply and demand. And Iām not afraid to say it!
Hereās the kicker: I even use supply and demand when talking about labor markets, even though all the hip labor economists are using monopsony models š¤·āāļø Am I not hip?!
The fact that PhD economists within any subfield have moved beyond the benchmark tells me almost nothing about what I should teach first-years. Macroeconomists are using heterogeneous agent DSGE models, IO economists are doing dynamic entry, and theorists are doingā¦ well letās not worry about the theorists.
There is always a trade-off between realism (which complicates the model) and tractability (which simplifies the model). After years of practice with formal models, realism becomes relatively cheaper, so the producers of models optimally choose more of it. But I guess if we havenāt taught our students about standard, competitive producer theoryātrading off inputs while taking competitive prices as givenāthey may not be able to see this š¤
But if the specialists are using one model, Iāa mere theoristāfeel the need to argue for why I focus on supply and demand so much when teaching about labor markets. I see four key results that are easy to show Econ 101 students without the complication of monopsony.
People respond to higher wages predictably, aka labor supply curves slope up.
Wages reflect productivity, aka demand curves for labor shift out with increased productivity.
Technology raises the productivity of workers who use the technology, aka the falling cost of a complementary good shifts out the labor demand curve for certain workers.
Higher returns to skills increase the demand for those skills, driving up the price of things like college.
There are lots of qualifications/subtleties that we can debate about these results. But this is 101 people! We need to establish the baseline before we attack it.
Supply Slopes Up
To start things off simple, I take a little time to assure my students that labor markets are similar to what we have studied so far. Despite the theoretical intrigue of backward bending labor supply curves and the fun dreaming of getting paid $1 million per hour and working for a minute each day, for real people on the relevant part of the wage distribution, they respond in predictable fashions to wages: when they get paid more, they work more. Supply curves slope up.
(Graphs come from a wonderful talk by Kevin Murphy.)
When my students are managing workers in 15 years, I hope they can remember that to get their employees to work more or harder, they made need to pay them more. Yes, thatās common-sense, but letās start easy: workers respond to price incentives.
Higher Productivity Increases Demand
We can also say a lot about the demand for labor, using the standard model. For example, we can show that wages are not arbitrary. There are economic forces (see what I did there?) that tie together a workerās wage and productivity for the company. Now, it need not be perfectly tied, as in competitive markets, for supply and demand to be helpful in understanding the broader point.
The key is that the demand curve for labor comes from the workerās ability to produce goods. When a worker is more productive, her wages increase.
Notice I am not saying that ONLY productivity affects wages. One doesnāt need to be an absolutist about the most basic example of the perfectly competitive model. Other things matter: preferences, bargaining power, etc. But no serious economist is going to suggest that an increase in the productivity of the marginal worker will not increase wages. That comes out of supply and demand; I donāt need anything fancier.
Complements Affect Productivity
Productivity is not only determined by how hard someone works, how much they slack off. There is a myriad of other factors that make workers more or less productive. Two deserve mention here: capital and technology.
As societies accumulate more capital and tools for working, workers become more productive. My father, when he still farmed, could harvest more corn in an hour than his father, not because he worked harder, but because he had modern equipment. That equipment raised his productivity. In jargon, the tractor was a complement to his labor.
More than physical capital, the long-run increases have come from technological advances. Society has learned through trial and error how to better produce things.
But this technology and capital may not increase everyoneās productivity identically. Take the example of a modern laptop (a combination of both capital and technology). A computer makes an engineer much more productive. It does little for a janitor. This will play out in wages. If we think education roughly corresponds to ālikeliness to have a job that uses computersā, the wage gains will go to higher education people, which we do see. That means the premium of a college education over high school will increase. And what do you know?š
Markets are Connected
The real power of supply and demand comes from studying across markets. Give me any data about price and quantity in the labor market and I can come up with a story of how the curves shifted to rationalize that. And Iām not even a creative economist.
But the real insight is not about the single market graphed, but what it can tell you about other markets. Since we are all trying desperately to be relevant to our students. Whatās more relevant than understanding the cost of education?
Suppose I observe the returns to college increasing. I donāt even need to know why. What does that do to the demand for college? Demand shifts out. What happens to the price? The price goes up š¤Æ Itās all, everybody in unison now, āSUPPLY AND DEMAND!ā
So I can quickly explain two major developments in labor markets (the growing returns to education and the growing cost of education) with good old supply and demand. There are interesting questions about how market power plays into this, but is someone really going to look me in the eye and say these are bigger trends than technological change?
Now I could explain these phenomena with a more complicated model, such as monopsony. But why complicate it? Why?! Itās not necessary. Students already get confused with two curves. I donāt need to add a third curve for no payoff. Thatās probably why Iāve found no intro textbook that talks about shifts of the curves in a monopsony model. Basically, all the monopoly/monopsony model in an intro textbook does is say āthis is why the price may not equal marginal cost.ā
Thatās important to remember. And it is why I teach monopoly and monopsony. But few 101 students can āuseā that model to derive any additional results.
So Iāve been able to explain the major labor market development of the last forty yearsāgrowing inequality across the wage distributionāwith supply and demand. That seems like a good use of time in the classroom. ā Oh, and Iāve explained why college is so damn expensive, which seems relevant to my students. ā ā
If other professors think the effects of minimum wage laws on employment numbers is the most important take away from economics 101, fine. Start with the monopsony model š I just beg, please, first ask what are the important economic ideas that I want to convey to students and THEN how can I make the model simple enough (but not too simple) to convey that idea.
-Brian
Thanks for reading š
Feel free to tell me Iām behind the times in the comments below š»
Tap the ā¤ļø and share with your friends (or enemies) š
I'm wondering if any students point out that the first graph of hours worked doesn't actually show which way the causation goes. Possibly, workaholics tend to also do things that results in them getting higher-paying jobs, and paying other workers more wouldn't cause them to work longer hours. Or some other factor results in both longer hours and higher wages.
It seems like it shouldn't be too hard to find a way to show causation, though?
Hey Brian, I'm with you! But I'm curious, is anyone going so far as to not start with supply and demand in 101?